1 / 15

Cap-and-Trade Programs: Lessons for California’s Carbon Regulations

Cap-and-Trade Programs: Lessons for California’s Carbon Regulations. James Bushnell University of California Energy Institute. Quantity Mechanisms Standards vs. cap-and-trade.

duncan
Download Presentation

Cap-and-Trade Programs: Lessons for California’s Carbon Regulations

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Cap-and-Trade Programs:Lessons for California’s Carbon Regulations James Bushnell University of California Energy Institute

  2. Quantity MechanismsStandards vs. cap-and-trade • Under what conditions would command and control approaches achieve environmental goals at the same total cost as a permit program? • Every source has the same cost of clean-up • The problem of costly retrofitting and technology innovation • More generally: when potential gains from shifting clean-up across sources (or technologies) are outweighed by the transaction costs of the program

  3. Hypothetical marginal cost of abatement curve for NOx 3. Low NOx burners for power plants with gas turbines ($1500/ton) Dollars per unit of abatement 1. Low NOx burners for power plants with steam turbines ($1000/ton) $1500 $1200 2. Mid-kiln firing for cementmanuf ($1200/ton) $1000 100 110 120 Abatement (`000s tons)

  4. Standards can produce largedifferences in compliance costs Power Plants Refineries $/unit $/unit MCApp MCA MCAv MCA Abatement (tons) Abatement (tons) Q standard Q standard

  5. Trades Reduce Emissions at less costly sources Power Plants Refineries Qtrade $/unit $/unit MCApp MCAv MCA MCA Qpollution Qpollution Qpollution Abatement (tons) Abatement (tons) Pollution (tons) Pollution (tons)

  6. Trades Reduce Emissions at less costly sources Power Plants Refineries Qtrade $/unit $/unit MCApp MCAv MCA MCA Qpollution Qpollution Qpollution Qpollution Abatement (tons) Abatement (tons) Pollution (tons) Pollution (tons)

  7. “Gains” from Emissions Trade Power Plants Refineries Qtrade Qtrade $/unit $/unit Savings MCApp MCAv Costs Qpollution Qpollution Abatement (tons) Abatement (tons) Pollution (tons) Pollution (tons)

  8. Factors that favor cap-and-trade • Significant variation in mitigation costs across sources • Large uncertainty about cost heterogeneity • potential for innovation in mitigation alternatives • Pollution effects are comparable across sources • Damage is not completely localized • upwind/downwind problem • Low Monitoring Costs • To date programs limited to stationary sources • Continuous monitoring costs $124,000/plant • All current programs targeted at sources • Not much experience with offsets (negative emissions) • Regulatory jurisdiction captures the relevant market • “Leakage” from regulated to unregulated sources or regions • Firms have comparable incentives to reduce compliance costs

  9. Monitoring Issues: • We’re pretty good at measuring output from stationary sources • It is not possible to meaningfully measure the “sources” of physical electricity consumed • Load-based must focus on financial transactions • It is easier to deceive regulators about financial transactions than physical emissions • MRTU and the “common” pool • Assignment of output from plants via accounting • “Exports” from within California (MW greenwashing)

  10. Firm Incentives and Cap-and-Trade • Basic model assumes all firms have equivalent incentives to reduce emissions costs • Firms can face differing incentives • Regulatory treatment of firms • Merchant vs. cost-of-service • Market power • In permits or in the product produced • Allocation mechanisms can distort incentives • The problem with endogenous allocations • These factors can lead to a distortion in who mitigates emissions, and by how much.

  11. Nox control summary statistics Regulated electricity markets (87,828 MW; 286 Units) Restructured electricity markets (88,370 MW; 302 Units) Data sources: EPA CEMS, EIA 767/860, ICAC, MJ Bradley and Associates.

  12. Cap-and-Tradeand coverage areas • Regions must be “big” enough • Induce liquidity in trades, take advantage of cost differences • Limit market power (RECLAIM problems) • Reduce leakage problems (GHG problems) • Regions must not be too big • Coverage should match damage or else “hot spots” can form • Pollution migrates up wind (or clean-up happens “downwind”) • East-coast Nox SIP-call program

  13. Nox Flow Patterns and Concentrations  1997 8 hour standard: 80 ppb

  14. Concluding Thoughts • In several ways, carbon is an ideal candidate for cap-and-trade, if applied on a sufficiently large scale • These policies will be interacting with other more directed regulations • These may lmit the scope for cap-and-trade to influence choices • Focusing on getting “real” reductions from California may miss the point • California is a drop in the carbon bucket • Leakage may not matter that much in the big picture • Must have a program that extends beyond California and the US • What policies would most impact other states and Countries?

More Related