250 likes | 334 Views
Soaring global interest in Farmland how can mozambique benefit? . Maputo, Feb. 10, 2011. Klaus Deininger, World Bank. The global picture. Daewoo to cultivate Madagascar land for free. Commodity price rise triggers land demand. Investor demand in Africa unprecedented.
E N D
Soaring global interest in Farmlandhow can mozambique benefit? Maputo, Feb. 10, 2011 Klaus Deininger, World Bank
Daewoo to cultivate Madagascar land for free Commodity price rise triggers land demand
A large danger of neglecting rights • Determinants of a country attracting investor interest/actual implementation
Actual land transfers lower but still large Total area transferred, no of projects and share of domestic investors, 2004-2009 Investment is often not predominantly foreign. Many ventures did not start production – thus positive impacts limited.
Why has success been so limited? • Gaps in legal & policy framework • Requires expropriation/extinction of existing rights (e.g. ZMB) • Unclear/duplicative institutional responsibility (e.g. ETH) • Low land payments/participation; non-collection (e.g. LBR) • Requirements for liquidating non-profitable investments rarely considered • Weak institutional capacity & implementation • Lack of information & consultation -> Neglect of property rights • Neglect of economic/technical viability (e.g. GHA) • Limited capacity to do or monitor ESIAs (e.g. SDN) • Weak land administration -> Boundary conflicts, overlap • Agreements are not written/monitored • Communities with little voice, capacity, and ability to resist • Negative effects shifted to locals who receive damage but no benefits • Non-viable projects encroach on local rights to make ends meet • Vulnerable & women left out –poor people subsidize (foreign) speculators • Historical examples of this leading to conflict or revolution
Boundary of allocated land 1 km Boundary misaligned with road Allocation over existing smallholders No visible large-scale cultivation despite transfer 5 yrs ago An example from Zambia
Countries that fared better did 3 things • Assessing potential and integrating it into their development strategy • Rather than having ad-hoc decisions by investors determine the country’s future • Identify suitable & off-limits areas as well as suitable crops (demand, endowment) • Strategically provide infrastructure (roads, research) • Link with local factor endowments, development strategy, and aspirations • Securing existing property rights & allowing their voluntary transfer • Development is for local people & unlikely to be promoted by expropriation • Often at group/community level: Need internal rules & outside representation (TZN) • Well-defined mechanisms to transfer all or part of local land (PER) • Clear demarcation of land & scope for transfer of unsuccessful ventures (MEX) • Implementing transparent processes & effective ways of monitoring/redress • Avoiding traps of rent seeking, corruption, and another resource curse • Auction of public land: Technical review, down-payments & investor vetting (PER) • Publication of contracts (LBR) can allow learning and independent monitoring • Build on initiatives to set technical standards & independent monitoring (RSPO; EP) • Incentives to avoid merely speculative land acquisition
Assessing potential: Methodology & use • Identify potential per crop & grid cell (5’ or 1 km resolution) • Data on soil, slope, elev., rainfall, temp. to simulate crop growth • Output prices for ‘local’ output value; transport cost for global price -> ‘best’ crop • Input prices to compute net profit & implicit land rental value • Cultivated land -> yield gap (actual/potential output) • Productivity increase often only option; may be cheaper & socially more appropriate • Area expansion risky & costly (soil tests, investment, compensation) • Yield gap can be attributed to technology, infrastructure & institutions • Leave options for expansion of existing farms (e.g. via mechanization) • ‘Uncultivated’ land -> possibly available/of interest to investors • Identify areas of highest potential/threat, opportunity cost & need for scrutiny • Priority areas for tenure regularization • Land rental surface can form a basis for negotiation • Investors benefit from that knowledge – and in Brazil make lots of money from it • The scenario used below • Rainfed Maize, soy, wheat, sugar, cassava, groundnut, oilpalm; high input intensity • Exclude forested & protected areas; levels of population density (5, 10, 25/km2)
Mozambique has considerable potential Source: IIASA
Land ‘availability’ by country • World total • 445 Mn ha (< 25/km2) • 306 Mn ha (< 10/km2) • 198 Mn ha (< 5/km2) • Key characteristics • Highly concentrated • > 90% in 32 countries • Half of these in Africa • Large rel. to current area • > double in 11 countries • > triple in 6 countries • Sheer size is instructive • Multiple constraints likely • Need sophisticated investors • Potential social dislocation
Illustrative expansion potential by crop Top countries with maize expansion potential (<25/km2) • Latin America’s advantages • Technology & land for expansion • Human capital • Infrastructure & market access • Institutions: • Property rights secure • Thriving land markets • Transparency • Contract enforcement • Financial markets • Africa’s opportunity • Borrow technology • Focus on regional markets • Expand from existing production • Rel. low opportunity cost of land * • Challenges to be overcome • Institutions • Mix of large & small • Public and private sector roles
Available options differ by country • Africa • Latin America & Caribbean
A typology of agrarian structure • Type 1 (Korea, China, Vietnam, India) • Significant gains from technology & institutional change by smallholders in the past • Intensification & (private sector) value addition as only sources of on-farm growth • Off-farm employment a main engine for increases in farm sizes via (rental) markets • Type 2 (Brazil, Argentina, Peru) • Technological barriers to large farm expansion low - big recent investment inflows • Land markets function relatively well, currently danger of bubbles • Regulation needed to avoid distributional, environmental & social externalities • Type 3 (Malawi, Rwanda, El Salvador) • High yield gap often a consequence of past underinvestment • Land is a key safety net; danger of people being pushed out with no alternative • Private investment to complement public initiative; contract farming • Type 4 (Sudan, Tanzania, Zambia, Mozambique) • Mechanization & larger farm size can be sustainable; incentive for private sector • Institutions (property rights & land markets) a key challenge • Factor market imperfections, if unchecked, can cause dualism & conflict
Policy focuses on the right issues • Agricultural zoning (1:1 Mn; ongoing at 1:250,000) to assess potential • Based on identification of agro-ecological suitability • Excluding productive forest, parks, cult. area, protected areas, concessions • -> Identify blocks of land possibly ‘available’ for investors • Property rights rightly recognized as a key pillar • Recognition of community occupancy rights; option of delimitation • Process for negotiation with investors • Land policy forum to explore key legislative & regulatory issues • Investors’ DUATs conditional on compliance with investment plan • Implement transparent processes & effective monitoring/redress • Establishment & gradual decentralization of CEPAGRI • Format for investment processing (res 70/2008) & process to vet proposals • Efforts to better regulate consultation process • Increasingly vigilant monitoring of investor compliance • Cleaning and consistency of data from provincial offices
But challenges remain • Zoning may be too narrowly focused on land availability only • Local strategy/understanding how to close yield gap needed required • Access to markets & technology has a key role; concessions underutilized • The exercise could yield vastly more insights • Land rights ‘recognition’ de facto often irrelevant • Lack of demarcation makes rights invisible • Land system serves a small minority & excludes women • Land transfers costly & uncertain even where they are allowed • Processes often costly & ineffective • Process for individualization/mutation ill-defined • Consultations deficient (few people, actas incomplete) • ‘Plan compliance’ costly to ascertain & easy to abuse • Structures often duplicative & centralized • Registry & cadastre operate in parallel spheres • Low/non-collected fees ($0.8/a) foster land speculation • Whatever revenues exist do not accrue to local gov’t Yield gap for maize
Background • 1997 law recognizes community rights – good legal basis • Huge potential: 34 mn. ha arable land; only 3.7 mn. ha cropped • Want to attract investors • New applications for 13 mn. ha in 18 months • Land audit: > 50% of existing awards of land use rights (DUATs) un- or underutilized • … then backtracking • Moratorium in 2008 • Identify available land first Overlaps can create problems Limited delimitation
The potential is enormous • Use global methodology to get land prices • Large variation over space • Overall level surprisingly high: Prices > $ 3,000/ha • Considerable potential around Beira (transport) • This area has currently low level of cultivation • Cultivated areas • Average profits about $ 500/ha • Compared to current value of < $ 100 • Poverty impact of closing yield gap & expansion immense • Concessions • Even higher potential ($ 700/ha) • But half of them are underutilized • Need cheap models to check (satellite imagery) • Rental fees could yield revenue & discourage speculation • Feed into local revenue; expand land rights Residual land values; high input scenario A A A A A A
It may be useful to explore options for .. • Using zoning information to feed into a broader rural development strategy • Identify yield gap & overlay with pop. density/poverty to define strategic options • Add prices & transport cost to potential for actual & potential profits & land values • Use this to evaluate potential impact of infrastructure improvement • Making occupancy rights relevant and exploring options for land transfer • Use information from ‘top-down’ zoning to feed into ‘bottom up’ land use planning • Define ‘community’, its representation, and its land rights (vs. individuals) • Eliminate dualism of rights through systematic low-cost delimitation/titling • Assess leasing options and study other countries’ experience (Vietnam, China) • Focusing on low-cost & incentive compatible monitoring/enforcement • Reduce cost & eliminate dualism by unifying registry & cadastre • Design low-cost compliance monitoring to cancel non-compliant DUATs (Brazil) • Ensure community consultation is informed, inclusive, and results in clear contract • Let lease payments benefit land owners & be determined by local level negotiation • Use part of fees to maintain system to make secure land rights accessible to all