290 likes | 388 Views
Crisis, Contagion, and the Need for a New Paradigm. Imagining an Economics That Works. Joseph E. Stiglitz Lindau August 26, 2011. Failures of Modern Macro-economics. Didn’t predict the financial crisis Standard models assert that bubbles can’t happen
E N D
Crisis, Contagion, and the Need for a New Paradigm Imagining an Economics That Works Joseph E. Stiglitz Lindau August 26, 2011
Failures of Modern Macro-economics • Didn’t predict the financial crisis • Standard models assert that bubbles can’t happen • Standard models assert that shocks are exogenous • Key “disturbance” to the economy was endogenous • Policy frameworks suggested that (a) keeping inflation low was necessary, and almost sufficient, for stability and growth; (b) government didn’t have instruments to prevent bubbles; (c) cheaper to clean up mess after bubble broke • Even after bubble burst, economists claimed effects “contained” • because of diversification • because markets have good “buffers”
Failures (cont.) • Responses to crises (based on advice from economists) have clearly been inadequate • High unemployment 4 years after beginning of recession • Standard models didn’t focus on credit—and therefore didn’t have much to say on repairing credit system • But theory of banking provided micro-foundations (including incentives of banks and bankers) • Policies ignored lessons of this literature (Greenwald-Stiglitz, 2003) • Even less to say on inherent deficiencies in securitization • Questionable improvements in risk diversification • Unambiguous attenuation of incentives (selection, monitoring, enforcement) • Some market participants took advantage of information asymmetries • Remarkable testimony to inefficiency, irrationality of markets that market participants did not recognize these (and other) problems • Including risk of increased leverage • Market didn’t seem to learn lesson of Modigliani-Miller
Failures (cont.) • Moreover, countries that have had highest persistent unemployment include those with allegedly most flexible labor markets (e.g. US), in contradiction to standard theory • But consistent with earlier studies of volatility • Easterly, W., R. Islam, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 2001a, “Shaken and Stirred: Explaining Growth Volatility,” in Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics 2000, Washington: World Bank, pp. 191-212. • —— , ——, and —— , 2001b, “Shaken and Stirred: Volatility and Macroeconomic Paradigms for Rich and Poor Countries,”, in Advances in Macroeconomic Theory, Jacques Drèze (ed.), IEA Conference Volume, 133, Palgrave, 2001, pp. 353-372.
Failures (cont.) • There were large losses associated with misallocation of capital before the bubble broke. It is easy to construct models of bubbles. But most of the losses occur after the bubble breaks, in the persistent gap between actual and potential output • Standard theory predicts a relatively quick recovery, as the economy adjusts to new “reality” • New equilibrium associated with new state variables (treating expectations as a state variable) • And sometimes that is the case (V-shaped recovery) • But sometimes the recovery is very slow • Persistence of effects of shocks • Explained by slow recovery of balance sheets (Greenwald-Stiglitz, 1993, 2003) • But current persistence is greater than can be explained by these models
Understanding what has happened • There have been large (and often adverse) changes in the economy’s risk properties, in spite of supposed improvements in markets • Moving from “banks” to “markets” predictably led to deterioration in quality of information • Increased interdependence has led to more financial fragility • The global economy is undergoing a major structural transformation • structural transformations may be associated with extended periods of underutilization of resources • Associated with deep market failures • Important role for government to facilitate transformation • See J.E. Stiglitz, 2011, “Rethinking Macroeconomics: What Failed and How to Repair It,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(4), pp. 591-645.
Does Interconnectivity lead to more or less systemic stability? • Standard answer: spreading of risk, with concavity, leads to better outcomes • But economic systems are rife with non-convexities—e.g. bankruptcy • Interlinked systems are more prone to system wide failures, with huge costs • privately profitable transactions may not by socially desirable (Greenwald-Stiglitz, "Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete Markets," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(2), pp. 229-64. 1986) • May lead to systemic risk • This crisis illustrates the risk
Incoherence in standard macro-frameworks • Argue for benefits of diversification (capital market liberalization) before crisis • Worry about contagion (worsened by excessive integration) after crisis • Optimal system design balances benefits and costs • “Contagion, Liberalization, and the Optimal Structure of Globalization,” Journal of Globalization and Development, 1(2), • “Risk and Global Economic Architecture: Why Full Financial Integration May be Undesirable,” American Economic Review, 100(2), May 2010, pp. 388-392.
An Analogous Problem • With an integrated electric grid the excess capacity required to prevent a blackout can be reduced • alternatively, for any given capacity, the probability of a blackout can be reduced. • But a failure in one part of the system can lead to system-wide failure • in the absence of integration, the failure would have been geographically constrained • Well-designed networks have circuit breakers, to prevent the “contagion” of the failure of one part of the system to others.
A simple example ), In autarky, where and Vari2. We normalize by choosing our units so that.
Simple example (cont.) Polar case where there is no value of risk diversification—production is linear in , provided is greater than some critical number *, at which point system failure occurs, and a loss of – occurs. The main concern then is to minimize the losses from system failure.
Simple example (cont.) • Assume that with probability , with probability , such that , i.e. expected output without bankruptcy is zero, but if , the country goes bankrupt, with output , where . • Prior to liberalization, expected output is • Assume , and there is full liberalization , i.e. • We focus on this case—small probabilities of “disaster”
Liberalization is unambiguously welfare decreasing • With liberalization, i.e. both countries go bankrupt if only one country has a bad outcome, and expected output (per country) is
Basic insight: even with mean preserving reductions in risk associated with risk pooling, the probability of any particular country falling below the bankruptcy threshold may increase with economic integration
Some General Results • Full integration never pays if there are enough countries • Optimal sized clubs • Restrictions on capital flows (circuit breakers) are desirable
Formally, two effects: • Trend reinforcement—negative shocks move us down further (equity depletion) • Modeling using stochastic differential equations, with probability that at any given time an agent goes bankrupt modeled as problem in first passage time • With trend reinforcement, there is an optimal degree of diversification • Battiston, Stefano, DomenicoDelliGatti, Mauro Gallegati, Bruce Greenwald, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Liaisons Dangereuses: Increasing Connectivity, Risk Sharing, and Systemic Risk,” paper presented to the Eastern Economic Association Meetings, February 27, 2009, New York, NBER Paper No.
Financial interlinkages • Bankruptcy cascades (Greenwald and Stiglitz, 2003; Gale and Allen, 2001) • The bankruptcy of one firm affects the likelihood of the bankruptcy of those to whom it owes money, its suppliers and those who might depend upon it for supplies; and so actions affecting its likelihood of bankruptcy have adverse effects on others. • The “architecture” of the credit market can affect the risk that one bankruptcy leads to a sequence of others. • If A lends to B, B lends to C and C lends to D, then a default in D can lead to a bankruptcy cascade. • On the other hand, if lending all goes through a sufficiently well capitalized clearing house (a bank), then a default by one borrower is not as likely to lead to a cascade • But a very large shock which leads to the bankruptcy of the “clearing house” can have severe systemic effects • Further externalities are generated as a result of information costs and imperfections. • If unit i doesn’t fully know other units’ characteristics—including the relationships (contracts) of those with whom it engages in a relationship, including all the relationships with whom those are engaged, ad infinitum—it cannot know the risks of their honoring their contract. • Explains some of adverse effects of non-transparent over the counter credit default swaps
Asymmetric Patterns • Our canonical model also assumed symmetric relationships in which all ties/contracts were identical. • In the presence of convexities, such symmetric arrangements often characterize optimal designs. • But that is not so in the presence of non-convexities, and there are many alternative architectures. • For instance, a set of countries can be tightly linked (a “common financial market”) to each other, but the links among financial markets may be looser. The former is designed to exploit the advantages of risk diversification, the latter to prevent the dangers of contagion. • Circuit breakers might be absent in the former but play a large role in the relations among the “common markets.” • Different architectures may lead to greater ability to absorb small shocks but less resilience to large shocks
Reducing the set of admissible relationships and behaviors can have benefits • Reducing the scope for these uncertainties, • Reducing the potential for information asymmetries, • Reducing the burden on information gathering. • In large non-linear systems with complex interactions, even small perturbations can have large consequences • Understanding these interactions major research agenda • Broader research agenda: Design of optimal networks, circuit breakers: optimal degree and form of financial integration • Beginning of large literature
References • Allen, Franklin and Douglas Gale, “Financial Contagion,” Journal of Political Economy, 108(1), 2000, pp. 1-33. • Battiston, Stefano, DomenicoDelliGatti, Mauro Gallegati, Bruce Greenwald, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Liaisons Dangereuses: Increasing Connectivity, Risk Sharing, and Systemic Risk,” paper presented to the Eastern Economic Association Meetings, February 27, 2009, New York. • DelliGatti, Domenico, Mauro Gallegati, Bruce Greenwald, Alberto Russo, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Business fluctuations in a credit-network economy” Physica A, 370 (2006), pp. 68-74. • DelliGatti, Domenico, Mauro Gallegati, Bruce Greenwald, Alberto Russo, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 2006, “Business Fluctuations in a Credit-Network Economy,” Physica A, 370, pp. 68-74. • —— , —— , —— , ——, and ——, 2009, “Business Fluctuations and Bankruptcy Avalanches in an Evolving Network,” Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination, 4(2), November, pp. 195-212. • De Masi, Giulia, Yoshi Fujiwara, Mauro Gallegati, Bruce Greenwald, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, forthcoming, "An Analysis of the Japanese Credit Network," Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review. • Gai, Prasanna and SujitKapadia, 2010a, “Contagion in Financial Networks,” Proceedings of the Royal Society A, 466(2120), pp. 2401-2423. • —— and ——, 2010b, “Liquidity hoarding, network externalities, and interbank market collapse,” mimeo, Bank of England. • Gallegati, Mauro, Bruce Greenwald, Matteo G. Richiardi, Joseph E. Stiglitz, “The Asymmetric Effect of Diffusion Processes: Risk Sharing and Contagion,” Global Economy Journal 8(3), 2008
Greenwald, Bruce and J. E. Stiglitz, Towards a New Paradigm of Monetary Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003 • Jeanne, Olivier and Anton Korinek, 2010, “Excessive Volatility in Capital Flows: A Pigouvian Taxation Approach,” American Economic Review, 100(2), pp. 403–407. • Haldane, Andrew G., 2009, “Rethinking the Financial Network,” address to the Financial Students Association, Amsterdam, April, available at http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2009/speech386.pdf (accessed September 22, 2010). • Haldane, Andrew G. and Robert M. May, 2010, “Systemic risk in banking ecosystems,” University of Oxford mimeo. • Korinek, Anton, 2010a, “Regulating Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: An Externality View,” working paper, University of Maryland. • ——, 2010b, “Hot Money and Serial Financial Crises,” working paper, University of Maryland, presented at the 11th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference, November 4-5. • ——, 2011, “Systemic Risk-Taking: Amplification Effects, Externalities, and Regulatory Responses,” working paper, University of Maryland.
Structural Transformation • Great depression was structural transformation from agricultural to manufacturing—this is a structural transformation from manufacturing to services • Productivity growth well in excess of growth in demand • Implying decrease in demand • If labor gets “trapped” in declining sector, then income will decline
Technical change always can induce large distributive consequences • Standard models ignore these • With perfect markets, winners can compensate losers — but they seldom do • With imperfect markets, decrease in welfare of those in “trapped sector” has spill over effects on others • And especially if there are efficiency wage effects, there can be adverse macro-economic consequences
Basic Model • Two sectors (industry, agriculture) • is the labor force in agriculture,is the labor force in industry; • is productivity in agriculture; • is demand from those in sector for goods from sector ; • is the (fixed) efficiency wage in the urban sector; • is the level of investment (assumed to be industrial goods); • is the price of agricultural goods in terms of manufactured goods, which is chosen as the numeraire; and • is the level of employment (); and • where we have normalized the labor force at unity.
Basic Results Theorem 1: If 1) the steady state is stable 2) the income elasticity of the demand for food by rural workers is small enough, 3) cA (the marginal propensity to consume manufactures by agricultural households) is sufficiently greater than cM (the comparable marginal propensity to consume of manufacturing households) then an increase in agricultural productivity unambiguously yields a reduction in the relative price p and in employment in manufacturing.
Results • The result of mobility-constrained agricultural sector productivity growth is an extended economy-wide slump. • Theorem 2: Under the stability condition, an increase in government expenditure increases urban employment and raises agricultural prices and incomes • Theorem 3: Under the stability condition an decrease in urban real product wages increases urban unemployment and lowers agricultural prices and incomes
Note irrelevance of standard model • Since such structural transformations occur very seldom, rational expectation models are not of much help • Since the central issue is structural, aggregate model with single sector not of much help • Since among major effects are those arising from redistribution, a representative agent model is not of much help • Since central issue entails frictions in mobility, assuming perfect markets is not of much help • Problems exacerbated by efficiency wage effects
Policy Implications • There should be structural policies to facilitate the movement of labor that is "trapped" in a dying sector • Even though structural policies are partof the solution, traditional Keynesian policies play a role • Contrast to those who are now claiming that most of the remaining unemployment is structural – there is a new "normal" to which we must now accommodate ourselves – and therefore policies designed to stimulate the economy may not only be useless, they may be counterproductive. • Such policies were at the center of recovery from Great Depression
Reference Domenico Delli Gatti; Mauro Gallegati; Bruce C. Greenwald; Alberto Russo; Joseph E. Stiglitz, “SectoralImbalances and Long Run Crises,” presented to IEA meeting, Beijing, July, 2011.