670 likes | 762 Views
Kidney Exchange. Al Roth Market Design, Fall 2008. Economists As Engineers . A certain amount of humility is called for: successful designs most often involve incremental changes to existing practices, both because
E N D
Kidney Exchange Al Roth Market Design, Fall 2008
Economists As Engineers • A certain amount of humility is called for: successful designs most often involve incremental changes to existing practices, both because • It is easier to get incremental changes adopted, rather than radical departures from preceding practice, and • There may be lots of hidden institutional adaptations and knowledge in existing institutions, procedures, and customs.
A general market design framework to keep in mind: • To achieve efficient outcomes, marketplaces need make markets sufficiently • Thick • Enough potential transactions available at one time • Uncongested • Enough time for offers to be made, accepted, rejected, transactions carried out… • Safe • Safe to participate, and to reveal relevant preferences • Some kinds of transactions are repugnant…and this can constrain market design.
Kidney exchange--background • There are over 75,000 patients on the waiting list for cadaver kidneys in the U.S. • In 2007 32,452 patients were added to the waiting list, and 25,879 patients were removed from the list. • In 2007 there were 10,587 transplants of cadaver kidneys performed in the U.S. • In the same year, 4,472 patients died while on the waiting list (and more than 1,300 others were removed from the list as “Too Sick to Transplant”. • In 2007 there were also 6,039 transplants of kidneys from living donors in the US. • Sometimes donors are incompatible with their intended recipient. • This opens the possibility of exchange .
A classic economic problem: Coincidence of wants (Money and the Mechanism of Exchange, Jevons 1876) Chapter 1: "The first difficulty in barter is to find two persons whose disposable possessions mutually suit each other's wants. There may be many people wanting, and many possessing those things wanted; but to allow of an act of barter, there must be a double coincidence, which will rarely happen. ... the owner of a house may find it unsuitable, and may have his eye upon another house exactly fitted to his needs. But even if the owner of this second house wishes to part with it at all, it is exceedingly unlikely that he will exactly reciprocate the feelings of the first owner, and wish to barter houses. Sellers and purchasers can only be made to fit by the use of some commodity... which all are willing to receive for a time, so that what is obtained by sale in one case, may be used in purchase in another. This common commodity is called a medium, of exchange..."
Section 301,National Organ Transplant Act (NOTA), 42 U.S.C. 274e 1984: “it shall be unlawful for any person to knowingly acquire, receive or otherwise transfer any human organ for valuable consideration for use in human transplantation”.
Charlie W. Norwood Living Organ Donation Act Public Law 110-144, 110th Congress, Dec. 21, 2007 • Section 301 of the National Organ Transplant Act (42 U.S.C. 274e) is amended-- (1) in subsection (a), by adding at the end the following: • ``The preceding sentence does not apply with respect to human organ paired donation.''
“Incentive Compatibility”: 2-way exchange involves 4 simultaneous surgeries.
Kidney exchange clearinghouse design Roth, Alvin E., Tayfun Sönmez, and M. Utku Ünver, “Kidney Exchange,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 2, May, 2004, 457-488. ________started talking to docs________ ____ “Pairwise Kidney Exchange,”Journal of Economic Theory, 125, 2, 2005, 151-188. ___ “A Kidney Exchange Clearinghouse in New England,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 95,2, May, 2005, 376-380. _____ “Efficient Kidney Exchange: Coincidence of Wants in Markets with Compatibility-Based Preferences,”American Economic Review, June 2007, 97, 3, June 2007, 828-851
And in the medical literature Saidman, Susan L., Alvin E. Roth, Tayfun Sönmez, M. Utku Ünver, and Francis L. Delmonico, “Increasing the Opportunity of Live Kidney Donation By Matching for Two and Three Way Exchanges,”Transplantation, 81, 5, March 15, 2006, 773-782. Roth, Alvin E., Tayfun Sönmez, M. Utku Ünver, Francis L. Delmonico, and Susan L. Saidman, “Utilizing List Exchange and Undirected Donation through “Chain” Paired Kidney Donations,”American Journal of Transplantation, 6, 11, November 2006, 2694-2705. Rees, Michael A., Jonathan E. Kopke, Ronald P. Pelletier, Dorry L. Segev, Matthew E. Rutter, Alfredo J. Fabrega, Jeffrey Rogers, Oleh G. Pankewycz, Janet Hiller, Alvin E. Roth, Tuomas Sandholm, Utku Ünver, and Robert A. Montgomery, “The First Never-Ending Altruistic Donor Chain,” April, 2008. Rees, Michael A., Alvin E. Roth, Tuomas Sandholm, M Utku Unver, Ruthanne Hanto, and Francis L. Delmonico, “Designing a National Kidney Exchange Program,” April, 2008.
Kidney Exchange—Creating a Thick (and efficiently organized) Market Without Money • New England Program for Kidney Exchange—approved in 2004, started 2005. • Organizes kidney exchanges among the 14 transplant centers in New England • Ohio Paired Kidney Donation Consortium, Alliance for Paired Donation (Rees) • 60 transplant centers and growing… • National (U.S.) kidney exchange—2009?? • Looks like it’s on the way (with some questions still about how well it will be designed and executed)
Graft Survival Rates 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 82 64 Percent Survival n T1/2 Relationship 47 2,129 3,140 2,071 34,572 39.2 16.1 16.7 10.2 Id Sib 1-haplo Sib Unrelated Cadaver 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Cecka, M. UNOS 1994-1999 Years Post transplant
Live-donor transplants have been much less organized than cadaver transplants • The way such transplants are typically arranged is that a patient identifies a willing donor and, if the transplant is feasible, it is carried out. • Otherwise, the patient remains on the queue for a cadaver kidney, while the donor returns home. • In many cases, the donor is healthy enough to donate a kidney, but has blood-type or immunological incompatibility with the patient. • Prior to 2004, however, in a small number of cases, additional possibilities have been utilized, given the success of transplants from unrelated donors: • Paired exchanges: exchanges between incompatible couples (only 5 in the 14 transplant centers in New England) • Two 3-way exchanges in Baltimore at Hopkins • Indirect exchanges: an exchange between an incompatible couple and the cadaver queue
Kidney Exchange • Important early papers: • F. T. Rapaport (1986) "The case for a living emotionally related international kidney donor exchange registry," Transplantation Proceedings 18: 5-9. • L. F. Ross, D. T. Rubin, M. Siegler, M. A. Josephson, J. R. Thistlethwaite, Jr., and E. S. Woodle (1997) "Ethics of a paired-kidney-exchange program," The New England Journal of Medicine 336: 1752-1755.
How might more frequent and larger-scale kidney exchanges be organized? • Building on existing practices in kidney transplantation, we consider how exchanges might be organized to produce efficient outcomes, providing consistent incentives (dominant strategy equilibria) to patients-donors-doctors. • Why are incentives/equilibria important? (becoming ill is not something anyone chooses…) • But if patients, donors, and the doctors acting as their advocates are asked to make choices, we need to understand the incentives they have, in order to know the equilibria of the game and understand the resulting behavior. • Experience with the cadaver queues make this clear…
Incentives: liver transplants Chicago hospitals accused of transplant fraud 2003-07-29 11:20:07 -0400 (Reuters Health) CHICAGO (Reuters) – “Three Chicago hospitals were accused of fraud by prosecutors on Monday for manipulating diagnoses of transplant patients to get them new livers. “Two of the institutions paid fines to settle the charges. ‘By falsely diagnosing patients and placing them in intensive care to make them appear more sick than they were, these three highly regarded medical centers made patients eligible for liver transplants ahead of others who were waiting for organs in the transplant region,’ said Patrick Fitzgerald, the U.S. attorney for the Northern District of Illinois.” • These things look a bit different to economists than to prosecutors: it looks like these docs may simply be acting in the interests of their patients…
Incentives and efficiency:Neonatal heart transplants • Heart transplant candidates gain priority through time on the waiting list • Some congenital defects can be diagnosed in the womb. • A fetus placed on the waiting list has a better chance of getting a heart • And when a heart becomes available, a C-section might be in the patient’s best interest. • But fetuses (on Mom’s circulatory system) get healthier, not sicker, as time passes and they gain weight. • So hearts transplanted into not-full-term babies may have less chance of surviving. Michaels, Marian G, Joel Frader, and John Armitage [1993], "Ethical Considerations in Listing Fetuses as Candidates for Neonatal Heart Transplantation," Journal of the American Medical Association, January 20, vol. 269, no. 3, pp401-403
First pass (2004 QJE paper) • Shapley & Scarf [1974] housing market model: n agents each endowed with an indivisible good, a “house”. • Each agent has preferences over all the houses and there is no money, trade is feasible only in houses. • Gale’s top trading cycles (TTC) algorithm: Each agent points to her most preferred house (and each house points to its owner). There is at least one cycle in the resulting directed graph (a cycle may consist of an agent pointing to her own house.) In each such cycle, the corresponding trades are carried out and these agents are removed from the market together with their assignments. • The process continues (with each agent pointing to her most preferred house that remains on the market) until no agents and houses remain.
Theorem (Shapley and Scarf): the allocation x produced by the top trading cycle algorithm is in the core (no set of agents can all do better than to participate) • When preferences are strict, Gale’s TTC algorithm yields the unique allocation in the core (Roth and Postlewaite 1977).
Theorem (Roth ’82): if the top trading cycle procedure is used, it is a dominant strategy for every agent to state his true preferences. • The idea of the proof is simple, but it takes some work to make precise. • When the preferences of the players are given by the vector P, let Nt(P) be the set of players still in the market at stage t of the top trading cycle procedure. • A chain in a set Nt is a list of agents/houses a1, a2, …ak such that ai’s first choice in the set Nt is ai+1. (A cycle is a chain such that ak=a1.) • At any stage t, the graph of people pointing to their first choice consists of cycles and chains (with the ‘head’ of every chain pointing to a cycle…).
The cycles leave the system (regardless of where i points), but i’s choice set (the chains pointing to i) remains, and can only grow i
Incentives and congestion • For incentive and other reasons, such exchanges have been done simultaneously. • Roth et al. (2004a) noted that large exchanges would arise relatively infrequently, but could pose logistical difficulties.
Suppose exchanges involving more than two pairs are impractical? • Our New England surgical colleagues have (as a first approximation) 0-1 (feasible/infeasible) preferences over kidneys. • (see also Bogomolnaia and Moulin (2004) for the case of two sided matching with 0-1 prefs) • Initially, exchanges were restricted to pairs. • This involves a substantial welfare loss compared to the unconstrained case • But it allows us to tap into some elegant graph theory for constrained efficient and incentive compatible mechanisms.
Pairwise matchings and matroids • Let (V,E) be the graph whose vertices are incompatible patient-donor pairs, with mutually compatible pairs connected by edges. • A matching M is a collection of edges such that no vertex is covered more than once. • Let S ={S} be the collection of subsets of V such that, for any S in S, there is a matching M that covers the vertices in S • Then (V, S) is a matroid: • If S is in S, so is any subset of S. • If S and S’ are in S, and |S’|>|S|, then there is a point in S’ that can be added to S to get a set in S.
Pairwise matching with 0-1 preferences(December 2005 JET paper) • All maximal matchings match the same number of couples. • If patients (nodes) have priorities, then a “greedy” priority algorithm produces the efficient (maximal) matching with highest priorities (or edge weights, etc.) • Any priority matching mechanism makes it a dominant strategy for all couples to • accept all feasible kidneys • reveal all available donors • So, there are efficient, incentive compatible mechanisms in the constrained case also. • Hatfield 2005: these results extend to a wide variety of possible constraints (not just pairwise)
Efficient Kidney Matching • Two genetic characteristics play key roles: • ABO blood-type: There are four blood types A, B, AB and O. • Type O kidneys can be transplanted into any patient; • Type A kidneys can be transplanted into type A or type AB patients; • Type B kidneys can be transplanted into type B or type AB patients; and • Type AB kidneys can only be transplanted into type AB patients. • So type O patients are at a disadvantage in finding compatible kidneys. • And type O donors will be in short supply.
2. Tissue type or HLA type: • Combination of six proteins, two of type A, two of type B, and two of type DR. • Prior to transplantation, the potential recipient is tested for the presence of antibodies against HLA in the donor kidney. The presence of antibodies, known as a positive crossmatch, significantly increases the likelihood of graft rejection by the recipient and makes the transplant infeasible.
Incompatible patient-donor pairs in long and short supply in a sufficiently large market • Long side of the market— (i.e. some pairs of these types will remain unmatched after any feasible exchange.) • hard to match: looking for a harder to find kidney than they are offering • O-A, O-B, O-AB, A-AB, and B-AB, • |A-B| > |B-A| • Short side: • Easy to match: offering a kidney in more demand than the one they need. • A-O, B-O, AB-O, AB-A, AB-B • Not hard to match whether long or short • A-A, B-B, AB-AB, O-O • All of these would be different if we weren’t confining our attention to incompatible pairs.
Why 3-way exchanges can add a lot Maximal (2-and) 3-way exchange:6 transplants 3-ways help make best use of O donors, and help highly sensitized patients Patient ABO Donor ABO A B O A B O O B Patient ABO Donor ABO A A A B B A x Maximal 2-way exchange: 2 transplants (positive xm between A donor and A recipient)
Four-way exchanges add less (and mostly involve a sensitized patient) • In connection with blood type (ABO) incompatibilities, 4-way exchanges add less, but make additional exchanges possible when there is a (rare) incompatible patient-donor pair of type AB-O. • (AB-O,O-A,A-B,B-AB) is a four way exchange in which the presence of the AB-O helps three other couples… • When n=25: 2-way exchange will allow about 9 transplants (36%), 2 or 3-way 11.3 (45%), 2,3,4-way 11.8 (47%) unlimited exchange 12 transplants (48%) • When n=100, the numbers are 49.7%, 59.7%, 60.3% and 60.4%. • The main gains from exchanges of size >3 have to do with tissue type incompatibility. • We can get nice analytic upper bounds based on blood type incompatibilities alone, and here gains from larger exchange diminish for n>3.
The structure of efficient exchange • Assumption 1 (Large market approximation). No patient is tissue-type incompatible with another patient's donor • Assumption 2. There is either no type A-A pair or there are at least two of them. The same is also true for each of the types B-B, AB-AB, and O-O. • Theorem: every efficient matching of patient-donor pairs in a large market can be carried out in exchanges of no more than 4 pairs. • The easy part of the proof has to do with the fact that there are only four blood types, so in any exchange of five or more, two patients must have the same blood type.
Theorem: every efficient matching of patient-donor pairs can be carried out in exchanges of no more than 4 pairs. Proof: Consider a 5-way exchange {P1D1, P2D2, P3D3, P4D4,P5D5}. Since there are only 4 blood types, there must be two patients with the same blood type. • Case 1: neither of these two patients receives the kidney of the other patient’s donor (e.g. P1 and P3 have the same blood type). Then (by assumption 1) we can break the 5-way exchange into {P1D1, P2D2} and {P3D3, P4D4, P5D5}
Case 2: One of the two patients with the same blood type received a kidney from the incompatible donor of the other • W.l.o.g. suppose these patients are P1 and P2. Since P1 receives a kidney from D5, by Assumption 1 patient P2 is also compatible with donor D5 and hence the four-way exchange {P2D2, P3D3, P4D4, P5D5} is feasible. • Since P2 was compatible with D1, P1’s incompatibility must be due to crossmatch (not blood type incompatibiliby, i.e. D1 doesn’t have a blood protein that P1 lacks). So P1D1 is either one of the “easy” types • A-A, B-B, AB-AB, or O-O, or one of the “short types” • A-O, B-O, AB-O, AB-A, or AB-B • In either case, P1D1 can be part of a 2 or at most 3-way exchange (with another one or two pairs of the same kind, if “easy,” or with a long side pair, if “short” ). • (Note that this proof uses both mathematics and biology)
e.g. max number of transplants Other weights W(E) different from |E| would maximize other objectives
General exchange with type-specific preferences • General model • Transitive (possibly incomplete) compatibility relation • Computational complexity—finding maximal 2 and 3 way exchanges on general graphs is NP complete • But average problems solve quickly: Abraham, Blum, Sandholm software: Ready for 10,000 pairs…
Thicker market and more efficient exchange? • Establish a national exchange • Make kidney exchange available not just to incompatible patient-donor pairs, but also to those who are compatible but might nevertheless benefit from exchange • E.g. a compatible middle aged patient-donor pair, and an incompatible patient-donor pair with a 25 year old donor could both benefit from exchange. • This would also relieve the present shortage of donors with blood type O in the kidney exchange pool, caused by the fact that O donors are only rarely incompatible with their intended recipient. • Adding compatible patient-donor pairs to the exchange pool has a big effect: Roth, Sönmez and Ünver (2004a and 2005b)
Other sources of efficiency gains • Paired exchange and list exchange Deceased donor P1-D1 P3 P1-D1 P2-D2 Deceased donor P3
Other sources of efficiency gains • Non-directed donors ND-D P1 P2-D2 P1-D1 ND-D P3
The graph theory representation doesn’t capture the whole story Rare 6-Way Transplant Performed Donors Meet Recipients March 22, 2007 BOSTON -- A rare six-way surgical transplant was a success in Boston. NewsCenter 5's Heather Unruh reported Wednesday that three people donated their kidneys to three people they did not know. The transplants happened one month ago at Massachusetts General Hospital and Beth Israel Deaconess. The donors and the recipients met Wednesday for the first time.
Incentive issues • Individuals—simultaneous surgeries • Multi-transplant-center exchange • Participation • Impossibility theorem (complete information) • Partial Possibility theorems
Can simultaneity be relaxed in Non-directed donor chains? • “If something goes wrong in subsequent transplants and the whole ND-chain cannot be completed, the worst outcome will be no donated kidney being sent to the waitlist and the ND donation would entirely benefit the KPD [kidney exchange] pool.” (Roth et al. 2006, p 2704).
‘Never ending’ altruistic donor chains (non-simultaneous, reduced risk from a broken link) Since NEAD chains don’t need to be simultaneous, they can be long…if the ‘bridge donors’ are properly identified.
The First Never-Ending Altruistic Donor Chain (Rees, APD) July July Sept Sept Feb Feb Feb Feb March March 2007 2007 2007 2007 2008 2008 2008 2008 2008 2008 MI AZ OH OH OH MD MD MD NC MD OH 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 O O A A B A A A A AB AB O O A A B A A A A A 62 0 23 0 100 78 64 3 100 46 Cauc Cauc Cauc Cauc Cauc Hisp Cauc Cauc Cauc AA # * Recipient PRA Recipient Ethnicity Relationship Husband Wife Mother Daughter Daughter Mother Sister Brother Wife Husband Father Daughter Husband Wife Friend Friend Brother Brother Daughter Mother * This recipient required desensitization to Blood Group (AHG Titer of 1/8). # This recipient required desensitization to HLA DSA by T and B cell flow cytometry.